Client Monopsony versus Contractor Bargaining Power
These are the slides for a research seminar that covers topics like collusion, incomplete contracts and auctions, and frames procurement as a contest between clients and contractors over information about costs and prices, mediated by project complexity and contractual relationships. The PDF can be downloaded here.
Other relevant posts
Market structure in building and construction here
Project characteristics and classifications here
Do projects have internal markets? here
A blog about the past, present and future of the building and construction industry
Showing posts with label collusion. Show all posts
Showing posts with label collusion. Show all posts
Wednesday, 13 June 2018
Friday, 17 November 2017
Australian Competition Commission Investigating Construction
Increasing Focus on Building and Construction
In early 2017 the Australian
Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) put the building and construction
industry on its priority list, which identifies industries where the ACCC believes
there are sufficient reasons for more intensive monitoring and investigation. As
with any regulator the ACCC has limited resources, so this list indicates where
those resources are being directed. In particular, unfair contract terms and
misconduct were targeted as part of the key
enforcement and compliance priorities for 2017.
The ACCC is an
independent Commonwealth statutory authority responsible for enforcing consumer
protection and fair trading laws and for promoting competition under the Competition
and Consumer Act 2010. The ACCC investigates and prosecutes cartels and
other types of anticompetitive conduct. Recent investigations by the ACCC
into the industry include a 2015 inquiry into price fixing and cartel conduct
in the Canberra
construction industry and proceedings against the Construction, Forestry,
Mining and Energy Union for secondary boycott conduct.
Whatever the ACCC has on the building and construction industry
led to the establishment of a Commercial Construction Unit, a 14-member
specialist unit to investigate alleged anti-competitive conduct in the
commercial construction sector.
In a press release ACCC chairman Rod Sims said the unit would allow the
watchdog to focus on conduct of construction industry participants that might
raise concerns under federal competition and consumer law: “The types of
construction industry participants that could potentially be investigated by
the unit include builders, subcontractors, unions and industry associations. The
ACCC is aware that conduct in this sector has raised serious allegations of
misconduct over a number of years. The unit enables a strategic focus to be
given to work in this sector.
In a speech
earlier this year, when the unit and its work was disclosed, Rod Sims said “We
have some continuing investigations and we will put additional resources into
some of those matters, and additional inquiries we have been scoping, to
investigate fully some serious allegations of anti-competitive conduct.” Over
2017 the number of people in the unit has increased.
There are as yet no details of
the work of the unit, led by Jane Lin, or any current investigations. However, the
unit has been funded as part of the Government’s response to the 2015 Royal Commission
into Trade Unions, whose report was covered in this post, which found serious
issues of illegal conduct by both unions and contractors, and involvement of
organized crime in the industry.
There has also been a Memorandum
of Understanding signed between the ACCC and the Australian Building and
Construction Commission (ABCC), another independent statutory authority, established after the royal
commission by the Building and Construction Industry (Improving
Productivity) Act 2016. The ABCC is primarily responsible for industrial
relations and has successfully prosecuted a number of construction union
officials.
The ACCC and the ABCC both have regulatory roles and
responsibilities in relation to building and construction, and the work of the agencies
is often complementary as they are both concerned with monitoring and reporting
on the industry. The MOU identified issues where they intend to work together
as:
(a) compliance with the CCA by building contractors and
subcontractors covered by the Code for the Tendering and Performance of
Building Work 2016 (Building Code)
(b) collusive tendering by building contractors and
subcontractors covered by the Building Code
(c) other restrictive anticompetitive agreements between
participants in the building and construction sectors
(d) unfair contract terms and security of payment compliance.
With the background of the Royal
Commission report and the ongoing ABCC cases
against the CFMEU and/or officials, the ACCC will also continue to pursue the
union. Nevertheless, the Royal Commission produced plentiful evidence of
illegal behaviour by contractors and developers, so the ACCC can be expected to pursue
those lines of inquiry too.
Tuesday, 8 March 2016
Construction Industry Collusion
Christian Brockmann’s
Big Idea
The issue of
market power in the construction industry is not one that gets a lot of
discussion, despite the associated issues of competitive behaviour and
appropriate regulation. A distinctive contribution is Christian Brockmann’s
ideas on collusion and corruption, where three related arguments were made.
First he put forward an analysis of bidding for projects as an auction that typically
results in a price below marginal cost for the winning contractor. Second, he then
argues the logical response of contractors as bidders to this outcome is
collusion, which is illegal. Third, he identifies the auction and bidding process
as an abuse of market power by clients that should be regulated. It’s worth
reviewing Brockmann’s arguments and their validity, as he provides a somewhat
different perspective on the issue of construction industry collusion.
In a market with a single buyer, as with a building or construction
client, it is possible to gain market power through bargaining with potential
suppliers. Bargaining power is found in bilateral negotiations over terms and
conditions of supply between trading partners. In a bargaining framework buyer
power is the ability to extract concessions or a surplus from a supplier,
typically through individually negotiated discounts. Buyer power in this case is
the bargaining strength a buyer has with respect to suppliers with whom it
trades, where bargaining strength depends on the ability to credibly threaten
to impose an opportunity cost if it is not granted a concession. The most
important issue is therefore the relative bargaining power on the buyer and
seller sides of the negotiation.
Competitive
tendering, in Brockmann’s view, is the exercise of such bargaining power by
clients. By using an auction to select the winning bidder based on lowest price
(known as a first price sealed bid auction), projects are won by bidders who
are willing to sacrifice margins or have underestimated costs (the ‘winner’s
curse’). In this case the ‘individually negotiated discount’ would be the difference
between a contractor’s marginal cost and the market price for the project.
In a
first-price procurement auction, the low bidder is awarded the contract. In a
common-values auction, the cost of performing the contract is common to all
bidders but is uncertain, bids are based on estimates, and this sort of auction
can result in the winner’s curse. Therefore bidding estimated cost, on average,
results in a loss because the lowest of several independent estimates of the
true cost, on average, is less than the true value, and rational bidders avoid
the winner’s curse by bidding above their cost estimates.
The problem
with first-price sealed bid auctions is that increasing the bid too little
results in lost revenue to the contractor while too much loses the competition.
Also, the larger the number of bidders the less likely a bid at equilibrium
price will win. Brockmann argues that these sealed-bid auctions have four characteristics, and in the
estimating and bidding process all these effects will overlap and aggregate:
- Are biased with regard to estimating errors, driving the low-bid award price below equilibrium price;
- Are biased with regard to information, driving the low-bid award price below equilibrium price; this is especially true in a two-phase award process, when the auction is followed by price negotiations;
- Are biased with regard to uncertainty, resulting in over-optimistic assumptions and driving the award price below equilibrium price;
- As institutions are biased with regard to technology, driving the award price below equilibrium price.
In the diagram above P* is the equilibrium (market) price and Pa is the auction price. The outcome of the auction is a price below the equilibrium price, and this augments the clients’ surplus (C) by the same amount that it reduces the contractors’ surplus. In addition there is a decrease in both surpluses (A+B), a deadweight loss, which measures the reduction of social welfare. The reason the winning bid is below marginal cost is because tenderers cannot estimate their costs accurately, due to non-systematic errors across the work breakdown structure used to get estimates. If estimating errors are normally distributed the lowest bid will be below the mean price (in auction theory this is known as the ‘winner’s curse’, where the winning bid makes a loss), which can be taken as the market price. The curve on the right hand side of the graph is the distribution of costs of the tenderers, the mean price is P*.
Brockmann
concludes clients have buyer power, and the industry’s response to their use of
that power is to collude in a variety of ways. Although a list is not proof, widespread
evidence of collusion in the building and construction industry would suggest,
in many circumstances, this can be the case. For example:
- The Japanese dango system of market sharing on public works;
- The Dutch industry cartel (650 companies fined €239 by NMa in 2003);
- The lift and elevator cartel (EU Competition Commission €992 fine in 2007);
- Montreal’s ‘Fabulous 14’ control almost 80% of public work;
- The Scandinavian ‘Big 3’ do around 70% of all building and construction;
- 112 UK companies were caught in a price-fixing case in 2009;
- The steel, cement and concrete industries are repeat offenders for anti-competitive practices in many countries;
- Australian ACCC cases include fire installation, unsuccessful tender fees and housing contractors, and a 2015 Royal Commission uncovered illegal payments between contractors, unions and crime figures, as did the Charbonneau Commission in Montreal.
There are many other examples. Brockmann says For
contractors collusion “is a business decision and the players are business unit
managers” and “Individuals have only the chance to walk away from the game as
this will continue to be played by others”. In his view collusion is more of a
structural problem than an ethical dilemma, with large groups of contractors
involved individual decisions have no effect on the behaviour of the group.
Brockmann
also, uniquely as far as I know, argues for regulation of buyer power. How this
might be achieved is left as an open question that he does not discuss, beyond
noting the industry’s frequent encounters with competition regulators around
the world. However, he does discuss the difficulty in getting people to behave
ethically under these conditions of procurement through auctions and settlement
through claims and variations. While collusive behaviour by contractors is illegal,
he strongly believes many clients can and do behave unethically when
negotiating with contractors:
Why is it ethically acceptable that
buyers have such market power? Why is it acceptable they can use ‘shrewd’
negotiating tactics? Collusion is both an ethical and structural problem. It
will persist as long as the institutions of procurement are not changed, giving
both sides equal power and reinstituting perfect competition on the project
market through regulation of the buyer’s behaviour.
This is a challenging
argument that raises the role of clients in shaping the behaviour of the
industry. It is also a key factor in the important issue of improving
procurement processes. Nevertheless, despite the theoretical neatness of the
argument on auctions and estimating errors, there are more than a few points
that are controversial. Among these are:
- If competitive tendering produces undesirable outcomes, a proposition many would disagree with, should the bid closest to the mean be selected, or the second lowest bid as in a Vickrey auction? Or another alternative?
- How can perfect competition be found in the market for major projects when there are a limited number of credible bidders? Oligopolies are notoriously conducive to collusion.
- There is also the problem of information asymmetry. A well-informed client with a reasonably accurate estimate might well have an advantage over potential suppliers, but for the great majority of projects the clients are infrequent and inexperienced and could be disadvantaged.
The problems
of poorly informed clients and profitless contracting have a long history, in
the 1830s London builders refused to tender for many projects under the
building agreement in use at the time. Even earlier, Marshall Vauban, a military engineer and builder of
fortifications for the French monarchy, insisted suppliers should be selected
on quality not just on price. In a letter from 1685 to his Minister he
complained about buyer behaviour and delays due to budget cuts, and argued:
Breaking of contracts, failures to honour verbal agreements and new
adjudications, only serve to attract those firms which do not know which way to
turn, rogues and ignoramuses, and to make those with the knowledge and
capability of directing firms, beat hasty retreats.
I would add that they delay and
inflate considerably the cost of these works, which are the worst since these
cuts and the cheapness sought are imaginary. For the contractor is ruined … He
does not pay the merchants who supply the materials, pays badly his employees,
cheats on those he can, has only the worst, and since he is cheaper than the
others, uses the poorest materials, quibbles about everything and is always
crying for mercy …
… go back to plain dealing; pay
the price for the works and do not deny an honest salary to a constructor who
fulfills his duties; that will always be the best deal you can find.
While this
was, and is, good advice, clients and their advisers are deeply committed to tendering
and awarding the contract to the lowest bid, despite the fact that it is
unlikely a competitive tender will result in a fair price. The purpose of a
tender is price discovery, particularly for non-standard goods, and the
industry is adept at bidding low to win work then making a project profitable.
On the other
hand, the widespread evidence of collusive tendering and anti-competitive
practices undermines the rationale for such reliance on competitive tendering. When
you get situations like Japan and Holland, where industry associations have
facilitated market sharing agreements across the country, it’s pretty clear the
traditional system of tendering and contracting is deeply troubled.
Brockmann, C. 2011. Collusion and Corruption in the Construction
Sector, in Gerard de Valence (ed.), Modern
Construction Economics: Theory and Application, Oxford: Spon. Quote on page
59.
Letter
from Vauban cited by Callender, G. 2003. A Short History of Procurement, in P.
Nagel (ed.), Supply Chain Management: A
Procurement Perspective, Melbourne: Hargreen Publishing, 2-9.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)