Projects As Micro-Markets
Can an
individual project contain within it an internal, though temporary market? The
definition of a market found in a standard economics text is “any arrangement
in which the interaction of buyers and sellers determines the price and
quantity of goods and services exchanged”. By this criteria the act of
procurement, which is purchasing goods and services, is indeed a market transaction.
A market for
a single project is created by the client as they go through the procurement
process, regardless of the particular system or method of procurement followed.
The client is the buyer of a bundle of goods and services from the contractor/s
bidding or negotiating for the project, and their interaction on the scope
(quantity) and price of the project is resolved when the agreement or contract
is exchanged. In particular, the extent of market power held, gained or lost by
participants as the procurement process goes through the stages of pre-bid,
tender, final bid and negotiation, or some variation of those stages, is an
important factor.
A
distinction can be made between the market for a project, typically one of many
similar types of projects, and the market for the supply of the bundle of goods and
services required to deliver that specific project. Such a market is created by
a project manager or lead contractor as they organize the work and subcontract
the various specialized tasks. This could be called a micro-market, and it establishes
within the project an internal market.
If
procurement of a project creates an identifiable, though temporary,
micro-market for goods and services, what are the distinctive characteristics
of such a market? Clearly it is not like a conventional market described in a
textbook. The characteristics of markets are the number of buyers and sellers,
the distinctiveness and substitutability of products, forms of competition,
barriers to entry and concentration ratio, and the information and mobility of
customers. These market characteristics do not, however, neatly carry over to
industries with extensive subcontracting, such as building and construction,
for three reasons.
The first
reason is there is only one buyer, and in such a market with a single buyer it
is possible to gain market power through bargaining with potential suppliers.
Bargaining power is found in the bilateral negotiations over terms and
conditions of supply between trading partners. In a bargaining framework buyer
power is the ability to extract surplus from a supplier, typically through
individually negotiated discounts. However, because this bargaining power
cannot be exercised when suppliers are competitive, it is a countervailing
power and thus its use is constrained by circumstances.
Buyer power
is the bargaining strength a buyer has with suppliers with whom it trades,
where its bargaining strength depends on its ability to credibly threaten to
impose an opportunity cost if it is not granted a concession. The traditional
economic treatment of bargaining power uses the concept of outside options
available to buyers and sellers. The Australian Competition and Consumer
Commission describes these as “the outside option is the best option that
either the seller or buyer can achieve if they walk away from the
negotiations.” Strong outside options for a buyer, or weak outside options for
a seller, will be a major source of buyer power in a bilateral bargaining
framework.
The second
reason is that subcontractors are typically not engaged in a single
transaction, as in the market-based trades of instant exchange and settlement
envisaged in economics textbooks. The relationship between a large corporation
and its subcontractors is typically more durable and intensive than a market
relationship. This idea of ‘relational contracting’ has firms developing
long-term ties with contractors, often with a degree of mutual understanding
and trust that are not typical of market transactions. Instead of using the
market, the firm will rely on a trusted supplier, especially when their
relationship involves shared knowledge and learning.
Third, there
are ‘hybrid’ concepts, where relations between a head contractor and the
subcontractors are stable and continuous over fairly long periods of time and
only infrequently established through competitive bidding. A form
of-integration that largely makes the concept of relational exchange redundant.
The hybrid concept does not survive the reality of contractual obligations, however.
While there may be relational aspects to the organization of
production/projects between firms, the legal distinction between firms, markets
and other arrangements remains real, and the legal status of the firm has not
been undermined. Conceptual boundaries are not
contractual boundaries, and this distinction should not be ignored.
A different
approach to these long-term or continuous relationships is the idea that a
project creates an internal, temporary, micro-market for the goods and services
supplied by subcontractors. This temporary micro-market, or internal project
market, comes into formal existence after the procurement process has been
completed, a contract signed and the project become a defined, deliverable
building or structure (although there seems to be no good reason why this idea
could not be applied to any type of project, such as software or equipment
development).
In
fact, all this takes us back to Ronald Coase’s
original 1937 paper ‘The nature of the firm’. Coase was the first to argue that
markets and firms are alternative governance structures for economic
transactions. Importantly, the firm is a distinct legal entity, a ‘legal
person’ that enters into written or unwritten contracts. He argued the firm is
an organisation, rather than just a production function, and separated the
market from the firm with the ‘price mechanism’ on one hand and its
‘supersession’ on the other.
For Coase
the alternative to the firm was the coordination of self-employed individual
producers by the market, each being his or her ‘own master’. In the case of
subcontracting, this extended organization still coordinates production, but
within the temporary market created by the project. Like any other type of
market this internal, temporary micro-market created by a project will have a
range of characteristics and dynamics.
The basic
proposition behind this line of reasoning is the idea that project procurement
is a mechanism for creating an internal market. If this is the case, we can
utilise the elements of industry structure, competitive analysis and so on, that
have traditionally been applied at the firm level, to better understand
projects and their governance.